No. 00-12720.
254 F.3d 1014
June 20, 2001
UNITED PARCEL SERVICE OF AMERICA, INC., PETITIONER-APPELLANT,
v.
COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE, RESPONDENT-APPELLEE.
Appeal from a Decision of the United States Tax Court.(Tax Court No. 15993-95), Ruwe, Judge.
Wilson and Cox, Circuit Judges, and Ryskamp *fn1, District Judge.
The opinion of the court was delivered by: Cox, Circuit Judge.
As amended July 2, 1001
The tax court held United Parcel Service of America, Inc. (UPS) liable for
additional taxes and penalties for the tax year 1984. UPS appeals, and we
reverse and remand.
I. Background
UPS, whose main business is shipping packages, had a practice in the early
1980s of reimbursing customers for lost or damaged parcels up to $100 in
declared value. *fn2 Above that level, UPS would assume liability up to the
parcel's declared value if the customer paid 25per additional $100 in
declared value, the "excess-value charge." If a parcel were lost or
damaged, UPS would process and pay the resulting claim. UPS turned a large
profit on excess-value charges because it never came close to paying as
much in claims as it collected in charges, in part because of efforts it
made to safeguard and track excess-value shipments. This profit was taxed;
UPS declared its revenue from excess-value charges as income on its 1983
return, and it deducted as expenses the claims paid on damaged or lost
excess-value parcels.
UPS's insurance broker suggested that UPS could avoid paying taxes on the
lucrative excess-value business if it restructured the program as insurance
provided by an overseas affiliate. UPS implemented this plan in 1983 by
first forming and capitalizing a Bermuda subsidiary, Overseas Partners,
Ltd. (OPL), almost all of whose shares were distributed as a taxable
dividend to UPS shareholders (most of whom were employees; UPS stock was
not publicly traded). UPS then purchased an insurance policy, for the
benefit of UPS customers, from National Union Fire Insurance Company. By
this policy, National Union assumed the risk of damage to or loss of
excess-value shipments. The premiums for the policy were the excess-value
charges that UPS collected. UPS, not National Union, was responsible for
administering claims brought under the policy. National Union in turn
entered a reinsurance treaty with OPL. Under the treaty, OPL assumed risk
commensurate with National Union's, in exchange for premiums that equal the
excess-value payments National Union got from UPS, less commissions, fees,
and excise taxes.
Under this plan, UPS thus continued to collect 25per $100 of excess value
from its customers, process and pay claims, and take special measures to
safeguard valuable packages. But UPS now remitted monthly the excess-value
payments, less claims paid, to National Union as premiums on the policy.
National Union then collected its commission, excise taxes, and fees from
the charges before sending the rest on to OPL as payments under the
reinsurance contract. UPS reported neither revenue from excess-value
charges nor claim expenses on its 1984 return, although it did deduct the
fees and commissions that National Union charged.
The IRS determined a deficiency in the amount of the excess-value charges
collected in 1984, concluding that the excess-value payment remitted
ultimately to OPL had to be treated as gross income to UPS. UPS petitioned
for a redetermination. Following a hearing, the tax court agreed with the IRS.
It is not perfectly clear on what judicial doctrine the holding rests. The
court started its analysis by expounding on the assignment-of-income
doctrine, a source rule that ensures that income is attributed to the
person who earned it regardless of efforts to deflect it elsewhere. See
United States v. Basye, 410 U.S. 441, 450, 93 S.Ct. 1080, 1086, 35 L.Ed.2d
412 (1973). The court did not, however, discuss at all the touchstone of an
ineffective assignment of income, which would be UPS's control over the
excess-value charges once UPS had turned them over as premiums to National
Union. See Comm'r v. Sunnen, 333 U.S. 591, 604, 68 S.Ct. 715, 722, 92 L.Ed.
898 (1948). The court's analysis proceeded rather under the
substantive-sham or economic-substance doctrines, the assignment-of-income
doctrine's kissing cousins. See United States v. Krall, 835 F.2d 711, 714
(8th Cir.1987) (treating the assignment-of-income doctrine as a subtheory
of the sham-transaction doctrine). The conclusion was that UPS's redesign
of its excess-value business warranted no respect. Three core reasons
support this result, according to the court: the plan had no defensible
business purpose, as the business realities were identical before and
after; the premiums paid for the National Union policy were well above
industry norms; and contemporary memoranda and documents show that UPS's
sole motivation was tax avoidance. The revenue from the excess-value
program was thus properly deemed to be income to UPS rather than to OPL or
National Union. The court also imposed penalties.
UPS now appeals, attacking the tax court's economic-substance analysis and
its imposition of penalties. The refrain of UPS's lead argument is that the
excess-value plan had economic substance, and thus was not a sham, because
it comprised genuine exchanges of reciprocal obligations among real,
independent entities. The IRS answers with a before-and-after analysis,
pointing out that whatever the reality and enforceability of the contracts
that composed the excess-value plan, UPS's postplan practice equated to its
preplan, in that it collected excess-value charges, administered claims,
and generated substantial profits. The issue presented to this court,
therefore, is whether the excess-value plan had the kind of economic
substance that removes it from "shamhood," even if the business continued
as it had before. The question of the effect of a transaction on tax
liability, to the extent it does not concern the accuracy of the tax
court's fact-finding, is subject to de novo review. Kirchman v. Comm'r, 862
F.2d 1486, 1490 (11th Cir.1989); see Karr v. Comm'r, 924 F.2d 1018, 1023
(11th Cir.1991). We agree with UPS that this was not a sham transaction,
and we therefore do not reach UPS's challenges to the tax penalties.
II. Discussion
I.R.C. �� 11, 61, and 63 together provide the Code's foundation by
identifying income as the basis of taxation. Even apart from the narrower
assignment-of-income doctrine-which we do not address here-these sections
come with the gloss, analogous to that on other Code sections, that
economic substance determines what is income to a taxpayer and what is not.
See Caruth Corp. v. United States, 865 F.2d 644, 650 (5th Cir.1989)
(addressing, but rejecting on the case's facts, the argument that the
donation of an income source to charity was a sham, and that the income
should be reattributed to the donor); United States v. Buttorff, 761 F.2d
1056, 1061 (5th Cir.1985) (conveying income to a trust controlled by the
income's earner has no tax consequence because the assignment is
insubstantial); Zmuda v. Comm'r, 731 F.2d 1417, 1421 (9th Cir.1984)
(similar). This economic-substance doctrine, also called the
sham-transaction doctrine, provides that a transaction ceases to merit tax
respect when it has no "economic effects other than the creation of tax
benefits." Kirchman, 862 F.2d at 1492. *fn3 Even if the transaction has
economic effects, it must be disregarded if it has no business purpose and
its motive is tax avoidance. See Karr, 924 F.2d at 1023 (noting that
subjective intent is not irrelevant, despite Kirchman's statement of the
doctrine); Neely v. United States, 775 F.2d 1092, 1094 (9th Cir.1985); see
also Frank Lyon Co. v. United States, 435 U.S. 561, 583-84, 98 S.Ct. 1291,
1303, 55 L.Ed.2d 550 (1978) (one reason requiring treatment of transaction
as genuine was that it was "compelled or encouraged by business or
regulatory realities"); Gregory v. Helvering, 293 U.S. 465, 469, 55 S.Ct.
266, 267, 79 L.Ed. 596 (1935) (reorganization disregarded in part because
it had "no business or corporate purpose").
The kind of "economic effects" required to entitle a transaction to respect
in taxation include the creation of genuine obligations enforceable by an
unrelated party. See Frank Lyon Co., 435 U.S. at 582-83, 98 S.Ct. at 1303
(refusing to deem a sale-leaseback a sham in part because the lessor had
accepted a real, enforceable debt to an unrelated bank as part of the
deal). The restructuring of UPS's excess-value business generated just such
obligations. There was a real insurance policy between UPS and National
Union that gave National Union the right to receive the excess-value
charges that UPS collected. And even if the odds of losing money on the
policy were slim, National Union had assumed liability for the losses of
UPS's excess-value shippers, again a genuine obligation. A history of not
losing money on a policy is no guarantee of such a future. Insurance
companies indeed do not make a habit of issuing policies whose premiums do
not exceed the claims anticipated, but that fact does not imply that
insurance companies do not bear risk. Nor did the reinsurance treaty with
OPL, while certainly reducing the odds of loss, completely foreclose the
risk of loss because reinsurance treaties, like all agreements, are
susceptible to default.
The tax court dismissed these obligations because National Union, given the
reinsurance treaty, was no more than a "front" in what was a transfer of
revenue from UPS to OPL. As we have said, that conclusion ignores the real
risk that National Union assumed. But even if we overlook the reality of
the risk and treat National Union as a conduit for transmission of the
excess-value payments from UPS to OPL, there remains the fact that OPL is
an independently taxable entity that is not under UPS's control. UPS really
did lose the stream of income it had earlier reaped from excess-value
charges. UPS genuinely could not apply that money to any use other than
paying a premium to National Union; the money could not be used for other
purposes, such as capital improvement, salaries, dividends, or investment.
These circumstances distinguish UPS's case from the paradigmatic sham
transfers of income, in which the taxpayer retains the benefits of the
income it has ostensibly forgone. See, e.g., Zmuda v. Comm'r, 731 F.2d at
1417 (income "laundered" through a series of trusts into notes that were
delivered to the taxpayer as "gifts"). Here that benefit ended up with OPL.
There were, therefore, real economic effects from this transaction on all
of its parties.
The conclusion that UPS's excess-value plan had real economic effects
means, under this circuit's rule in Kirchman, that it is not per se a sham.
But it could still be one if tax avoidance displaced any business purpose.
The tax court saw no business purpose here because the excess-value
business continued to operate after its reconfiguration much as before.
This lack of change in how the business operated at the retail level,
according to the court, betrayed the restructuring as pointless.
It may be true that there was little change over time in how the
excess-value program appeared to customers. But the tax court's narrow
notion of "business purpose"-which is admittedly implied by the phrase's
plain language-stretches the economic-substance doctrine farther than it
has been stretched. A "business purpose" does not mean a reason for a
transaction that is free of tax considerations. Rather, a transaction has a
"business purpose," when we are talking about a going concern like UPS, as
long as it figures in a bona fide, profit-seeking business. See ACM P'ship
v. Comm'r, 157 F.3d 231, 251 (3d Cir.1998). This concept of "business
purpose" is a necessary corollary to the venerable axiom that tax-planning
is permissible. See Gregory v. Helvering, 293 U.S. 465, 469, 55 S.Ct. 266,
267, 79 L.Ed. 596 (1935) ("The legal right of a taxpayer to decrease the
amount of what otherwise would be his taxes, or altogether avoid them, by
means which the law permits, cannot be doubted."). The Code treats lots of
categories of economically similar behavior differently. For instance, two
ways to infuse capital into a corporation, borrowing and sale of equity,
have different tax consequences; interest is usually deductible and
distributions to equityholders are not. There may be no tax-independent
reason for a taxpayer to choose between these different ways of financing
the business, but it does not mean that the taxpayer lacks a "business
purpose." To conclude otherwise would prohibit tax-planning.
The caselaw, too, bears out this broader notion of "business purpose." Many
of the cases where no business purpose appears are about individual income
tax returns, when the individual meant to evade taxes on income probably
destined for personal consumption; obviously, it is difficult in such a
case to articulate any business purpose to the transaction. See, e.g.,
Gregory, 293 U.S. at 469, 55 S.Ct. at 267 (purported corporate
reorganization was disguised dividend distribution to shareholder); Knetsch
v. United States, 364 U.S. 361, 362-65, 81 S.Ct. 132, 133-35, 5 L.Ed.2d 128
(1960) (faux personal loans intended to generate interest deductions);
Neely v. United States, 775 F.2d 1092, 1094 (9th Cir.1985) (one of many
cases in which the taxpayers formed a trust, controlled by them, and
diverted personal earnings to it). Other no-business-purpose cases concern
tax-shelter transactions or investments by a business or investor that
would not have occurred, in any form, but for tax-avoidance reasons. See,
e.g., ACM P'ship, 157 F.3d at 233-43 (sophisticated investment partnership
formed and manipulated solely to generate a capital loss to shelter some of
Colgate-Palmolive's capital gains); Kirchman, 862 F.2d at 1488-89 (option
straddles entered to produce deductions with little risk of real loss);
Karr, 924 F.2d at 1021 (fa�ade of energy enterprise developed solely to
produce deductible losses for investors); Rice's Toyota World, Inc. v.
Comm'r,, 752 F.2d 89, 91 (4th Cir.1985) (sale-leaseback of a computer by a
car dealership, solely to generate depreciation deductions). By contrast,
the few cases that accept a transaction as genuine involve a bona fide
business that-perhaps even by design-generates tax benefits. See, e.g.,
Frank Lyon, 435 U.S. at 582-84, 98 S.Ct. at 1302-04 (sale-leaseback was
part of genuine financing transaction, heavily influenced by banking
regulation, to permit debtor bank to outdo its competitor in impressive
office space); Jacobson v. Comm'r, 915 F.2d 832, 837-39 (2d Cir.1990) (one
of many cases finding that a bona fide profit motive provided a business
purpose for a losing investment because the investment was not an obvious
loser ex ante).
The transaction under challenge here simply altered the form of an
existing, bona fide business, and this case therefore falls in with those
that find an adequate business purpose to neutralize any tax-avoidance
motive. True, UPS's restructuring was more sophisticated and complex than
the usual tax-influenced form-of-business election or a choice of debt over
equity financing. But its sophistication does not change the fact that
there was a real business that served the genuine need for customers to
enjoy loss coverage and for UPS to lower its liability exposure.
We therefore conclude that UPS's restructuring of its excess-value business
had both real economic effects and a business purpose, and it therefore
under our precedent had sufficient economic substance to merit respect in
taxation. It follows that the tax court improperly imposed penalties and
enhanced interest on UPS for engaging in a sham transaction. The tax court
did not, however, reach the IRS's alternative arguments in support of its
determination of deficiency, the reallocation provisions of I.R.C. �� 482
and 845(a). The holding here does not dispose of those arguments, and we
therefore must remand for the tax court to address them in the first instance.
III. Conclusion
For the foregoing reasons, we reverse the judgment against UPS and remand
the action to the tax court for it to address in the first instance the
IRS's contentions under �� 482 and 845(a).
REVERSED AND REMANDED.
RYSKAMP, District Judge, dissenting:
I respectfully dissent. Although I agree with the majority's recitation of
the facts as well as its interpretation of the applicable legal standard, I
find that its reversal of the tax court is contrary to the great weight of
the evidence that was before the lower court. The majority, as well as the
tax court below, correctly finds that the question before the Court is
whether UPS's insurance arrangements with NUF and OPL are valid under the
sham-transaction doctrine. Under the sham-transaction doctrine, UPS's
transaction ceases to merit tax respect when it has no "economic effects
other than the creation of tax benefits," Kirchman v. Comm'r, 862 F.2d
1486, 1492 (11th Cir.1989), or has no business purpose and its sole motive
is tax avoidance. See Karr v. Comm'r, 924 F.2d 1018, 1023 (11th Cir.1991).
Thus the question before the Court is not strictly whether UPS had a tax
avoidance motive when it formulated the scheme in question, but rather
whether there was some legitimate, substantive business reason for the
transaction as well. There clearly was not.
As the tax court articulated in great detail in its well-reasoned 114-page
opinion, the evidence in this case overwhelmingly demonstrates that UPS's
reinsurance arrangement with NUF and OPL had no economic significance or
business purpose outside of UPS's desire to avoid federal income tax, and
was therefore a sham transaction. First, the tax court based its decision
upon evidence that the scheme in question was subjectively motivated by tax
avoidance. For example, the evidence showed that tax avoidance was the
initial and sole reason for the scheme in question, that UPS held off on
the plan for some time to analyze tax legislation on the floor of the
United States House of Representatives, and that a letter sent to AIG
Insurance from UPS detailing the scheme claimed that AIG would serve in
merely a "fronting" capacity and would bear little or no actual risk. The
evidence thus showed that this scheme was hatched with only tax avoidance
in mind.
Second, the tax court based its decision on overwhelming evidence that
UPS's scheme had no real economic or business purpose outside of tax
avoidance. For example, the evidence showed that NUF's exposure to loss
under the plan (except in the very unlikely event of extreme catastrophe)
was infinitesimal, and that UPS nevertheless continued to fully bear the
administrative costs of the EVC program. NUF was only liable for losses not
covered by another insurance policy held by UPS, yet UPS still collected
the EVC's and deposited the money into UPS bank accounts, still processed
EVC claims, and continued to pay all EVC claims out of UPS bank accounts
(while collecting the accrued interest for itself). All NUF really did in
the scheme was collect over $1 million in fees and expenses before passing
the EVC income on to OPL, which was of course wholly owned by UPS
shareholders. In essence, NUF received an enormous fee from UPS in exchange
for nothing.
Moreover, the tax court systematically rejected every explanation of the
scheme put forth by UPS. UPS claimed that the scheme was meant to avoid
violation of state insurance laws, yet the evidence showed no real concern
for such laws and that in fact UPS was well aware that federal preemption
of these state laws likely made its old EVC plan legal. UPS claimed that it
intended OPL to become a full-line insurer someday, yet the evidence showed
that it was nevertheless unnecessary to specifically use EVC income for
such a capital investment. UPS claimed that elimination of the EVC income
allowed it to increase its rates, yet one of its own board members
testified that this explanation was untrue. I also note that UPS's claim
that OPL was a legitimate insurance company fails in light of the fact that
OPL was charging a substantially inflated rate for EVCs. Evidence in the
tax court showed that in an arms-length transaction with a legitimate
insurance company, EVC rates would have been approximately half those
charged by UPS (and in turn passed on to OPL), providing further evidence
that the transaction was a sham. In sum, UPS failed to show any legitimate
business reason for giving up nearly $100 million in EVC income in 1984.
For these reasons, I would affirm the holding of the tax court and find
that UPS's arrangement with NUF and OPL was a sham transaction subject to
federal tax liability.
Opinion Footnotes
1 Honorable Kenneth L. Ryskamp, U.S. District Judge for the Southern
District of Florida, sitting by designation.
2 These facts synopsize the high points of the tax court's long opinion,
which is published at 78 T.C.M. (CCH) 262, 1999 WL 592696.
Kirchman, which is binding in this circuit, differs in this respect
from the oft-used statement of the doctrine derived from Rice's Toyota
World, Inc. v. Comm'r, 752 F.2d 89, 91-92 (4th Cir.1985). Rice's Toyota
World, unlike Kirchman, requires a tax-avoidance purpose as well as a lack
of substance; Kirchman explicitly refuses to examine subjective intent if
the transaction lacks economic effects.